03 - Utility Demand function and Pricing - DME
03 - Utility Demand function and Pricing - DME
%%
[[2024-11-08]]
%%
In the following discussion, we will assume the costumer to be economically rational:
The costumer will always try to maximize:
- Consumption
- Utililazation
Utility function
Let
For simplicity, in this chapter we will work with only 2 goods:
We can visualize this in the following graph:
The area under the graph is the set of all possible combination of
The utility function is defined as follows:
The utility function, is a function
such that
It's a particular function. We are not as much interested in the absolute value of the function as much as we are in the relative value. We don't really care how much
Properties of the utility function
The #Utility function is continuous
The #Utility function is monotonically increasing on every single variable:
The second derivative exists and is always negative or equal to 0 (the function is cuasi-convex):
The #Utility function, calculated in the empty set (in
Types of utility function
Cobb-Douglas utility function
The Cobb-Douglas utility function has the following value:
where
are positive coefficients that measure the consumer preferences.
Quasilinear utility function
The Quasilinear utility function has the following expression:
where:
or
Linear utility function
The linear #Utility function is works well for [[#Perfectly substitutive goods]]:
where:
Other utility function
The other #Utility function works well for [[#Perfectly complementary goods]].
where:
Indifference curve
The indifference curve is the locus of points
Budget constrain
Let
the total budget available Respectively the unit prices of goods 1 and 2
Then
%%
[[2024-11-13]]
%%
Theory of election
,
What combination
Reminding that the consumer is rational, we have an optimization problem:
subject to:
The solution to the problem is given by the utility such that the iso-utility curve is tangent to the constraint, in the tangent point:
Relation of Marginal Substitution
In order to maintain the [[#Utility function]] constant, the ratio between the production of good 1 and good 2 needs to be equal to the Relation of Marginal Substitution:
Proof:
Keeping
From this we can write:
Notice that, in the optimum point, the ratio
q.e.d.
Particular cases
Perfectly substitutive goods
Two goods are perfectly substitutive when the consumer is willing to substitute one goods for an other with no change with a 1:1 ratio:
The arrow represents the direction in which the [[#Utility function]] increases
In this case, the utility function is well represented by a [[#Linear utility function]]
Perfectly complementary goods
Two goods are perfectly complementary if both are always consumed using fixed proportions.
The arrow represents the direction in which the [[#Utility function]] increases
In this case the [[#Utility function]] is well represented by the [[#Other utility function]].
Undesirable goods
A good is considered undesirable when the consumer does not accept it.
If
The arrow represents the direction in which the [[#Utility function]] increases
Demand function
A demand function (
where:
Demand of good Price of good Price of good different than Budget of the buyer (can be seen as costumer's income)
The demand has different patterns depending on the type of good:
As a function of prices, usually demand decreases as price increases
Griffen goods
Giffen goods are goods that, for some reason, have a demand that increases as price increases. This happens for example with some items during emergencies, when there is scarcity (remember face masks during covid).
Elasticity
In general, finding the [[#Demand function]] is quite difficult. Often times though, we are not really interested in knowing the full demand, but we can work at the local level. We maybe just need to know how the demand varies when changing the several factors. This introduces the concept of elasticity.
Let a demand be
Elasticity is defined as:
Elasticity is the ratio between percentage change of demand and price. It tells us how much the demand varies, for a given variation in price (see also Elasticità della domadna).
Types of elasticity
Perfectly elastic demand
A perfectly elastic demand is one where #Elasticity is infinite:
This means that, even the slightest change in price will make the demand completely different. Really, what it means is that, even keeping the price constant, makes the demand change freely.
Elastic demand
An elastic demand is one where the demand is sensitive to the price. Changing the price strongly affects the demand
Perfectly inelastic demand
A perfectly inelastic demand is one where for any change in price, the demand stays constant
Inelastic demand
An inelastic demand is one where even big change in prices, only cause small changes in demand.
Unitary elasticity
A demand with unitary elasticity is one where for any percentage change in price, the demand changes of the same percentage.
Theory of pricing
Social Welfare
Social Welfare is defined as the sum of #Consumer surplus and #Producer surplus
Let's imagine we have the following situation:
- A demand (
) that increases with the reducing in price - A supply (
) that increases with increase in price
The intersection of the 2 is an equilibrium point, called equilibrium price.
The equilibrium point is how much the costumer/consumer is pays in the current state of the market (with demand
Notice that, if the producer were to increase the supply, the price would increase. Same if the demand increased. This means that, in reality, the consumer is willing to pay more than
Consumer surplus
The consumer surplus is the cumulative amount that all the consumers are still willing to pay given the current market conditions. It's what they're willing to pay on top of what they're paying currently.
In the graph, the consumer suprlus can be seen as the area indicated in orange:
Producer surplus
The producer surplus is the amount of supply that the producer is still willing to provide.
In the graph, is the area in green
Cost, value, price
Let
where:
price cost (time) of user
From the user prospective we have:
Then, the price costumers are willing to pay at
We can then define:
#Consumer surplus:
CS = Willing to pay - cash - trip time
While, from the producer prospective:
In the graph we have:
The curve
The blue area is how much the costumers are cumulatively willing to pay.
The generalized cost for the user will be
The generalized cost for the user is the sum of the price (
If it costs the producer
The total social cost will be the sum of the orange and green areas.
While the net social benefit will be the willing to pay - social cost.
Pricing principles in transportation
Remember that the #Social Welfare is:
The Consumer Surplus is an average cost that mainly depends on the number of users (
The Producer Surplus will depend on:
Annual fix cost of the infrastructure Operating and maintenance costs Operative cost of vehicles
For simplicity:
Then, the #Producer surplus is the sum:
Maximizing the social welfare
In general, with transportation, we're interested in maximizing the #Social Welfare:
Where the SW:
This, according to what has been said before, can be written as:
where notice that, the term
To maximize this function, we calculate the first derivatives (in
Now,
And, remembering the definition of generalized cost:
we can write:
So:
❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗
❗❗❗ COMPLETARE ❗❗❗
❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗❗